The changes within world capitalism in the last thirty years since
the end of the postwar boom have brought a significant theoretical
discussion about both their scope and characteristics, and also
their consequences for the prospects outlined by revolutionary Marxism.
Thus, in the view of many contemporary thinkers, the globalisation
of capitalist production and the world market have brought to life
a new situation and a historical turn-about. This is the case with
Toni Negri, autonomism's main theoretician, who upholds such views
in his latest book, Empire, co-authored with Michael Hardt. They
define the latter as the globalisation's new political order. Contrariwise,
other theoreticians belonging to the school of historical sociology
of the world system argue that, ever since its beginnings, capitalism
has always operated as a world economy, thus rejecting the novelty
of globalisation as a mere misinterpretation of history. One of
the most notorious spokespersons of this strand is Giovanni Arrighi,
who in the mid 90s went on to publish The Long Twentieth Century,
a work where he poses such view. Such theoretical orientations challenge,
from different angles, the classical definition of imperialism,
such as it was formulated by Lenin and upheld by revolutionary Marxists
in the bygone twentieth century.
The significance of this debate lies in the fact that the new developments
call forth a reappraisal of the political, economical and social
events, as a way to validate the Marxist categories that have been
hammered out to grapple with the former. Regardless the changed
situation, the current debate resembles the bustling theoretical
and intellectual polemic that took place inside the international
socialist movement -and also beyond it-, as free- concurrence capitalism
grew into imperialism in the late nineteenth, early twentieth century.
In the light of these new debates, new fundamentals questions for
historical materialism and dialectics arise, to be able to grapple
with the new challenges posed by the complex reality of the world
and the new century. Such was Lenin's approach, who took up the
categories of dialectics to respond to the complex new questions
which had arisen out of the new phase of capitalism- the Great War
among them. Lenin did not confine himself to a scholastic repetition
of Marxist categories. Instead, he applied them to the new reality
in a creative manner, taking on board -albeit in a critical fashion-
insights furnished by his adversaries and co thinkers, such as Hilferding
or Kautky, and even by bourgeois liberal ideologues such as Hobson,
while ridding them of the reformist overtones infused by their authors.
In Lenin's view, it was a matter of putting together those breakthroughs,
building them into a new set-up that should highlight the revolutionary
potential enshrined within the new epoch then unfolding before his
eyes.
The two strands of thought we are taking issue with carry the merit
of being endeavours to furnish a global overview of contemporary
reality. However, the shortcomings of their theoretical approach
prevents them from accurately understanding, no matter the findings
and the genuine questions underpinning their contributions, the
shifts within the world order in the last thirty years. That is
why before dwelling on our own view, we shall make a critical appraisal
of Negri's and Arrighi's postulates, which in turn shall enable
us to understand better and more profoundly the classical Marxist
method, as it was postulated in the new epoch by Lenin and Trotsky.
In this article we will criticise the those two strands of thought
challenging the postulates on imperialism, taking up the materialist
dialectic approach to analyse world capitalism, in an updated view
that shall enable us to grapple with present-day reality.
The "Long Twentieth Century"
The purpose of this book is to set out how the decline of American
hegemony and the crisis of accumulation of the 70s (a reflection
of which was the flotation of the dollar that put an end to the
gold standard dictated by the Bretton Woods agreements, along with
the American defeat in Vietnam) have both been a watershed in the
history of world capitalism. In order to explain the shifts in the
world today, Arrighi claims that we have to go back and place this
crisis in the framework of the protracted record of cycles of capitalist
accumulation. Drawing on Ferdinand Braudel and his approach, Arrighi
builds up a massive analytical and historical work that tackles
with the four systemic cycles of capitalist accumulation, the four
"long centuries" which place the American century at the
end of a series of centuries- Genoa's, the Netherlands' and the
British century.
From this historical perspective, Arrighi shows that there is nothing
new to the crisis of the 70s. What capitalism is going through today
under America's rule, it had already been through under the domination
of the British, the Dutch before them, and the Genoese right at
the onset of capitalist expansion. The crisis points to a transition,
a watershed that has been common to every systemic cycle of accumulation,
in which there has been a first phase characterised by material
expansion, investment into production, then a second phase of financial
expansion, including speculation. Such transition to a financial
expansion, which in the author's view took place in the early 80s
in the American case, always bears an "atmosphere of doom"
(in Braudel's words), pointing to the end of a systemic cycle. It
also highlights the decline of American hegemony over the world
system, since in Arrighi's view the end of long century goes hand
in hand with a geographic shift of the heartland underpinning the
systemic process of capital accumulation. In his own words, "Shifts
of this kind have occurred through all the crises and financial
expansions that have borne their mark on the transition from a systemic
cycle of accumulation to another." Arrighi claims that the
U.S. has given way to Japan so that the latter will preside over
the coming long cycle of capitalist accumulation.
Arrighi: the rejection of the class struggle
as history's driving force
Arrighi's theoretical edifice on the series of systemic cycles of
accumulation supersedes the Marxian tenet regarding the class struggle
as the driving force of history. As with every cyclic theory, it
is not human action, the human agency, the one that shapes the course
of history, but the objective laws of capitalist accumulation. Change
is brought about by a structural build up of contradictions. Such
view on history precludes any chance of a revolutionary break up
and transformation within society, just allowing for a cyclical
repetition -although a more complex one every time- of the state
bodies and the capitalist enterprise, the dialectic between the
state and capital, the only agents of change within the historical
process perceived by Arrighi. The "systemic chaos" sparked
off by the end of the phase of capitalist accumulation and the onset
of the financial expansion of the hegemonic power that also provokes
an increased inter-state competition among the main powers and also
heightened social developments, always end up in the replacement
of an old hegemony by a new emerging state and economic power. The
outcome of this is a steady increase in the complexity, the size
and the might of the leading agencies of capitalist history, a process
that can be summed up as follows.
Thus, the Genoese regime was based upon a city-state of small size
and simple organization, which actually had very little power. Its
strength lay in its widespread commercial and financial links that
enabled it to deal with most of the mighty, territory-based European
rulers on an equal foot, and which were the at the base of its symbiotic
bond with the rulers of the kingdom of the Spanish peninsula.
The United Provinces were a much bigger and more complex organization
than their Genoese predecessor, a hybrid kind of organization combining
some features of medieval city-states now withering away with features
of the emerging nation-states.
Then, Arrighi claims, "Great Britain was not only a full blown
nation-state and, as such, a much bigger and more complex organization
than the United Provinces at any time; it was also conquering a
commercial and territorial empire of world dimensions that would
furnish its ruling circles and its capitalist class with an unprecedented
rule over the human and natural resources of the entire world."
Lastly, in the words of the same author, "
the U.S. were
already something more than a full-blown nation-state. They were
a continental industrial-military complex endowed with a power strong
enough so as to give efficacious protection to a number of subordinated
governments and allies, and to live up to its threats of economic
strangulation or military annihilation aimed at rival governments
anywhere in the world."
However, regardless of the valuable historical elements he contributes
with, such series of systemic cycles of accumulation whose origin
and evolution is governed by a self-repeating pattern fails to explain
away the actual operation of the capitalist mode of production.
As every cyclic theory does, it just describes a kernel of efficient
causes that fails to incorporate the driving forces at work behind
the motion, it just describes a contingent sequence of events. In
this way, Arrighi relapses in some sort of empiricism at odds with
historical materialism, for which the source of motion lies in the
contradiction and its laws of development arise from the process
of interpenetration of the opposing poles of the contradiction.
History and structure of the world capitalist
market
The outcome of such approach combining a changing hierarchy between
the state power and the capitalist enterprise is a view on the history
and the structure of the world capitalist market is an outright
rejection of the fact that its development contains within it the
existence of different relationships of production. In this way,
it confounds the development of the world market, brought to life
by merchant capital, a prerequisite for the unfolding of the capitalist
mode of production in the fringes of the feudal mode of production,
placing the origin the capitalist world market some 500 years ago,
along with the flourishing of the Italian city-states in the Renaissance.
Secondly, it overlooks the fact that the existence of the world
market can only be understood as the by-product of the consolidation
of the capitalist mode of production, as a dominant regime of production,
and that its setting up poses that "
an articulate system
of capitalist relationships of production, semi-capitalist and pre-capitalist
ones, linked to each other by capitalist relationships of exchange
and dominated by the world capitalist market." The coming to
life of the capitalist world market, with these features, can only
be found from the industrial revolution onwards, which took place
in the late eighteenth century, early nineteenth century.
In the third place, it puts and equal sign between the capitalist
economy and commodity exchange, overlooking the fact that under
capitalism, the distinctive feature is the pursuit of surplus value,
which is churned out of industrial production, being the latter
the driving force of the expansion of world commerce. In Marx's
words, "the world market constitutes in itself the basis for
this regime of production. On the other hand, its inherent need
to produce on an ever increasing scale contributes to the steady
expansion of the world market, therefore not being commerce the
one to spur industry, but contrariwise, the latter spurs commerce."
The conclusion of such theoretical schema is that it fails to differentiate
the phases of the development of capitalism. If outbound expansion
is a feature of the capitalist mode of production since the beginning,
i.e., since the industrial revolution, in the history of capitalism
in the last 200 years or so, we can see two phases. As Ernest Mandel
points out: "In the epoch of free concurrence capitalism, the
direct production of surplus value by big industry was confined
to Western Europe and North America. The process of primitive accumulation
of capital, however, was going on in many other places of the world
at the same time, never mind the tempo was uneven
Foreign capital,
of course, flowed into the countries which were industrializing
themselves, but was unable to take over the process of accumulation."
Mandel goes on, "In the epoch of imperialism there was a turn-about
in this whole structure. The process of primitive accumulation of
capital in the formerly non capitalistic economies was therefore
submitted to the reproduction of the big capital coming from the
West. From now on, the export of capital from the imperialist countries,
but not the process of original accumulation of capital, was to
shape the economic development of what later came to be known as
the 'Third World'. The latter was thus forced to meet the needs
of capitalist production in the metropolitan countries
The
process of imperialist export of capital thus suffocated the economic
development of the so-called 'Third World'
."
Arrighi and his theory of cycles overlooks this quantum leap in
the structure of capitalist accumulation worldwide. Quoting Ferdinand
Braudel -and discussing against a major feature of the classical
definition of imperialism, the emergence of finance capital (an
issue Lenin took from Hilferding)- he argues that: "Hilferding
regards the world of capital as a series of possibilities, within
which the finance type, a very recent outcome according to him,
has tended to prevail over the rest, penetrating them from within.
It is an opinion with which I would agree, with the reservation
that I understand that the plurality of capitalism goes well back
into time. Finance capitalism was no recently-born baby in the early
twentieth century. I would even argue that in the past, let us say,
in Genoa or Amsterdam
finance capital was already able to take
over and rule during some time at least, over all of the endeavours
of the business world." In this quotation, we clearly see how
the cyclic kernel of capitalist accumulation is completely misleading
when it comes to understanding the quantum leaps within that mode
of production. Such overlapping of historical epochs stems from
the weakness of the concepts. How can we compare the money capital
hoarded by the merchants living in the city-states of Italy and
the Netherlands, which was used to give loans to the several European
dynasties, with the surplus capital (churned out of big industry)
accumulated in the main developed countries in the late nineteenth
century, a by-product itself of the concentration and centralization
of capital within the boundaries of the nation-state had reached
its limit? Such surplus capital underpinned the unprecedented extension
of capital's geographic boundaries reaching out to the whole world.
Such outbound expansion of national capital inexorably led to a
chaotic competence for the resources, the markets and the control
of the routes for foreign trade, which are at the base of struggle
for the scramble of the world that reached momentum in the World
War I. This was nothing but a symptom that the development of the
productive forces had out flowed the borders of the nation-state,
that imperialism deepens the contradiction between the growth of
the productive forces of the world economy, and the borders separating
nations and states against each other. This is also a symptom, in
turn, that the contradiction between the qualitatively increased
social production, such as the monopolies which embraced vertically
under a single control different phases of production, and the private
appropriation of social wealth. Such structural contradictions,
inherent to the capitalist mode of production burst open in the
early twentieth century, thus ushering in a new phase of capitalist
development. This new phase of decline and agony does not preclude
the contradictions at work in the capitalist mode of production,
but incorporates additional laws presiding over its works. Arrighi,
with his theory of cycles, fails to understand this. But it was
Marx the one to point out that "The are special laws presiding
over the origin, the existence, the development and the death of
a given social organism, and also its replacement."
The onset of this new epoch had brought to life something new: the
first victorious proletarian revolution, the 1917 Russian Revolution.
Such extension of capital's domains, that bringing to life the mighty
reality of the capitalist world market, had ripened the objective
conditions that were to radically alter the nature of the epoch,
putting proletarian revolution right on the agenda. Ever since,
we cannot understand the dynamics of capitalist accumulation without
taking into account the powerful revolutionary leverage of the proletariat
and the oppressed worldwide. It is here where the schema furnished
by Arrighi collides head-on with the reality of the "long twentieth
century", one that was characterised by a persistent class
struggle, wars and revolutions, not only in those moments when "systemic
chaos" reigned supreme, using his own words, but when "material
expansion" was under way (such as the postwar boom). Those
have shattered the metropolitan countries from time to time, whereas
they have been present in the periphery continuously.
Following his own schema, Arrighi notes that "
as time
elapsed, the cycles have grown shorter. As we move on from the early
stages to the latter phases of capitalist development, the systemic
regimes of accumulation have taken less time to come to life, develop
and be superseded." This speeding up of history's tempo is
a fact of the contemporary world. However, Arrighi fails to understand
the fundamental reason for such shortening of history's tempo: the
social power accumulated by the workers movement and the masses,
and the upheaval of the colonial and semicolonial peoples in pursue
of their liberation. These two substantial elements have impinged
on the dynamics of capitalist rule in the century now bygone. That
is why in this book, it goes unnoticed to cast aside, in his own
words, "the class struggle and the polarization of the world
economy in peripheral and central areas, processes both that have
played a preeminent role in my original view of the long twentieth
century." In this way, with a one-sided approach, one of which
he is aware, he undoes the dialectic unity between the economy,
the inter-state relationships and the class struggle, the one and
only accurate starting point for an all-round understanding of today's
capitalism, and even the issue of the links between money and power,
an aimed pursued by Arrighi in this book.
Empire
In this book, Negri and Hardt hold that globalisation has brought
about a decline of sovereignty, since it relied on the nation-state,
and also an ever-decreasing ability to regulate the cultural and
economic exchanges: "The sovereignty of the nation-state was
the cornerstone of the imperialisms that European powers constructed
throughout the modern era. By 'Empire,' however, we understand something
altogether different from 'imperialism'. The boundaries defined
by the modern system of nation-states were fundamental to European
colonialism and economic expansion: the territorial boundaries of
the nation delimited the center of power from which rule was exerted
over exteral foreign countries through a system of channels and
barriers that alternately facilitated and obstructed the flows of
production and circulation. Imperialism was really an extension
of the sovereignty of the European nation-states beyond their own
boundaries." However, this does not mean the end of sovereignty
altogether, but the coming to life of a new type, made up of a whole
new series of national and supranational agencies, gathered together
by a new common logic of rule, such would be what they call Empire.
"In contrast to imperialism, Empire establishes no territorial
center of power and does not rely on fixed boundaries or barriers.
It is a decentered and deterritorializing apparatus of rule that
progressively incorporates the entire global realm within its open,
expanding frontiers". For them, these transformations in the
political order worldwide point to a shift within the capitalist
mode of production. It has put an end to the spatial divisions of
the "worlds" known under Yalta, the First World (western
powers), the Second World (the USSR and the European East) and the
Third World (semicolonial world), for it is now possible to find
the First World within the Third, the Third World within the First,
whereas the Second World is nowhere to be seen. This has gone hand
in hand with a transformation of the dominant productive process,
one in which the role played by industrial, factory-based labour
has by and large subsided, while communicative, cooperative and
affective labour have all become predominant. The outcome is that
"postmodernity" holds a firm grip on the global economy.
Against those who regard the U.S. as the ultimate source of authority
presiding over the unfolding of globalisation and the new world
order, either to praise it as the leader of the world and sole superpower,
or else those who loathe the renewed imperialist oppression, the
autonomist theoretician and his cothinker postulate that "Our
basic hypothesis, however, that a new imperial form of sovereignty
has emerged, contradicts both these views. The United States does
not, and indeed no nation-state can today, form the center of an
imperialist project. Imperialism is over.No nation will be world
leader in the way modern European nations were."
Antonio Negri and Michael Hardt: an overestimation
of the class struggle
If Giovanni Arrighi overemphasizes the role of the structure, up
to the point of writing off the human agency as the driving force
of social transformations, Negri and his literary fellow, Hardt
elevate the latter to unprecedented heights. Thus, Negri takes issue
against Arrighi in his Empire as follows: "What concerns us
more is that in the context of Arrighi's cyclical argument it is
impossible to recognize a rupture of the system, a paradigm shift,
an event. Instead, everything must always return, and the history
of capitalism thus becomes the eternal return of the same. In the
end, such a cyclical analysis masks the motor of the process of
crisis and restructuring. Even though Arrighi himself has done extensive
research on working-class conditions and movements throughout the
world, in the context of this book, and under the weight of its
historical apparatus, it seems that the crisis of the 1970s was
simply part of the objective and inevitable cycles of capitalist
accumulation, rather than the result of proletaran and anticapitalist
attack both in the dominant and in the subordinated countries. The
accumulation of these struggles was the motor of the crisis, and
they determined the terms and nature of capitalist restructuring."
We agree with Negri that the wave of working class and people's
struggles that swept through the imperialist countries, the bureaucratised
workers states and the semicolonial countries since the late 60s,
and that went through the following decade (although with ebbs and
tides), meant a shift in the balance of forces favourable for the
mass movement, a period where the oppressed moved to the offensive
against imperialism.
Notwithstanding that, one cannot say that "The accumulation
of these struggles was the motor of the crisis, and they determined
the terms and nature of capitalist restructuring." In this
way, he endows the class struggle with absolute powers, taking issue
against Arrighi -who abuses of the structural elements in his theoretical
postulates- in an abstract way. The inherent contradictions of the
capitalist mode of production, i.e., the relationship between the
development of the productive forces and the relationships of production
is downplayed because crises are regarded as the direct by-product
of the power of labour.
At a more general level, the agency and the structure are strongly
intertwined, and if one separates any of these poles, giving primacy
to one over another is a big mistake. To give an absolute value
to structural contradictions within the mode of production results
in a closed structure devoid of any chance of revolutionary transformation
through human action, therefore relapsing in a cyclic kernel, a
feature we have already taken issue with in Arrighi and the school
of the world system. Likewise, Negri's elevation of the class struggle
leads him to downplay the material contradictions that provide the
substrate for the class struggle to unfold. He also forgets that
the former becomes history's driving force when the structural contradictions
come to the surface. Such moments are the watersheds in history's
evolution. In other words, social developments play a predominant
role when the contradictions have ripened. In this sense, we agree
with an old polemic book by Anderson in which he claimed: "
according
to historical materialism, among the most fundamental mechanisms
of social change we find the systematic contradictions between the
productive forces and the relationships of production, and not only
social conflicts between the classes nourished by antagonistic relationships
of production. The former overlap with the latter because one of
the biggest forces of production is always labour, which in turn
constitutes a distinct class due to the relationships of production.
However, they do not coincide with each other. The crises of the
modes of production are not identical with the clashes between the
classes. They can fuse with each other occasionally. The onset of
major economic crises, both under feudalism and capitalism has often
caught the social classes unawares, since they stemmed from the
structural depths lying beneath the direct clash between them. On
the other hand, the resolution of such crises has been brought about
quite often as a result of protracted clashes between the classes.
As a matter of fact, the revolutionary transformations -from a mode
of production to another- are as a rule the privileged terrain for
the class struggle."
As to the 70s, the increased organic composition of capital boosted
during the boom and the subsequent fall in the rate in the profit,
plus political developments such as sharpened inter-imperialist
rivalries due to the emergence of powers like Germany and Japan
-in other words, a ripening of structural factors- were all causes
that pushed the exploited classes onto the scene worldwide. This,
in turn, dislodged the postwar world order. It also disrupted the
equilibrium between the states, the classes and inside the economy
that had allowed for the boom, thus ushering in a period of crisis
of accumulation for capital. Such crisis is the reflection of this
combination of elements, but not a direct reflection of the power
of labour.
In turn, this power of labour "dictates the terms and the nature
of capitalist restructuration". As Negri puts it in his work:
"The revolting masses, their desire for liberation, their experiments
to construct alternatives, and their instances of constituent power
have all at their best moments pointed toward the internationalization
and globalization of relationships, beyond the divisions of national,
colonial, and imperialist rule. In our time this desire that was
set in motion by the multitude has been addressed (in a strange
and perverted but nonetheless real way) by the construction of Empire.
One might even say that the construction of Empire and its global
networks is a response to the various struggles against the modern
machines of power, and specifically to class struggle driven by
the multitude's desire for liberation. The multitude called Empire
into being."
There is little doubt that the upsurge in the 70s aimed against
the two mainstays of the postwar order eroded the partition of the
world in three distinct areas (metropolitan countries, "the
second periphery" or the degenerate and deformed workers states,
and the semicolonial countries or the so-called "Third World")
that had shaped the class struggle during that historical period,
due to the grip of the counterrevolutionary apparatuses (socialdemocrats,
stalinists and bourgeois nationalists). The struggle waged by the
Vietnamese masses and the solidarity movement that emerged in the
imperialist countries, both of which paralysed the U.S. imperialist
military machine, was the most eloquent proof of this. We cannot
deny that that mass upsurge drove capital to seek for a response
in the direction of undermining the bases of the power of labour,
one that later on took the shape of the neoliberal offensive and
the so-called globalisation that goes hand in hand with it. But
claiming that the "terms and the nature of the capitalist restructuring"
were the direct result of such accumulation of struggles overlooking
the outcome of those fights is simply to glorify the class struggle
in itself. The moments of capitalist accumulation are determined
by the different phases and the corresponding shifts in the balance
of forces between the classes. During the "dress rehearsal"
back in 1968, although the industrial working class fought tooth
and nail, the proletariat was unable to find a solution for its
decade-long crisis of revolutionary leadership and thus could not
win decisive victories over imperialism. In failing to do so, they
gave time for it to rally its ranks, thus letting the unfolding
of the neoliberal offensive get through. Such policies set in the
early 80s, but the Brezhnev counterrevolution that had crushed the
1968 "Prague spring" and the Polish events a decade later
paved the way for them. To these, we should add the policy of the
CPs and the socialdemocracy that worked for the derailment of the
upsurge in France and Italy, as well as the anti-dictatorial struggles
in Portugal and Spain, and also the responsibility of the CPs in
the debacle of the revolutionary upheaval in South America.
Hinging upon this balance of forces, the endogenous mechanisms of
the capitalist accumulation gradually prevailed, i.e., the need
to offset the tendency of the rate of profit to fall through the
incorporation of new regions with cheap raw materials and labour,
the ceaseless search of superprofits by monopolies and the constant
technological revolution need for this, the wave of mergers and
acquisitions as a fetter to competition.
Both elements, the derailment and the defeat of the "accumulation
of struggles" in the 70s, and the imperialist backlash fuelled
by the crisis of accumulation, were to dictate the terms of the
capitalist restructuring, and not just the first element alone,
making abstraction of outcome of the class combats.
A ultrasubjectivist theory of a mysterious
and phantasmagoric subject
The downplaying of the structural contradictions inherent in the
capitalist mode of production and the overestimation of the subject
are manifested in the new theoretical scheme proposed by Negri and
Hardt to define the "Empire" as a new phase of capitalism
that leaves imperialism behind. Breaking up the dialectic unity
between the relationships of production and the class struggle,
they attempt a recreation of materialism that is vitiated by the
hypertrophy of the subject, a subjectivists theory where the structure
holds no barriers, it does not constraint the human agency, even
more, the former is a mere consequence of his action. This can be
clearly seen when the Italian philosopher and his literary co thinker
claim that: "Theories of the passages to and beyond imperialism
that privilege the pure critique of the dynamics of capital risk
undervaluing the power of the real efficient motor that drives capitalist
development from its deepest core: the movements and struggles of
the proletariat...History has a logic only when subjecitivity rules
it, only when (as Nietzsche says) the emergence of subjectivity
reconfigures efficient causes and final causes in the development
of history. The power of the proletariat consists precisely in this...The
old analyises of imperialism will not be sufficient here because
in the end they stop at the threshold of the analysis of subjectivity
and concentrate rather on the contradictions of capital's own developmet.
We need to identify a theoretical schema that puts the subjectivity
of the social movements of the proletariat at center stage in the
processes of globalization and the constitution of global order."
The emphasis between the role played by structural contradictions
and the conscious human agency, of working out organic crises, has
been displaced from the former to the latter throughout the centuries
through which the history of mankind has unfolded. In the epoch
of proletarian revolution, the subjective factor acquires a decisive
role. The transformation heralded by proletarian revolution constitutes
the most conscious step humanity has ever taken. The transition
from feudalism to capitalism, in a certain way, is in-between (in
the sense that the take over of the means of production comes before
the seizing of political power by the bourgeoisie) when compared
to the downfall of the Roman Empire and the Russian Revolution.
Nonetheless, in spite of the predominant role played by the subjective
factor -and its most developed form: the organization of the masses
in soviets as organs of power led by a revolutionary party- one
cannot appraise the outcome of these transformations through endowing
subjectivity with an absolute power as a change agent in the world.
Such is the view the Bolsheviks had of themselves: "
one
of the historical factors, its 'conscious' factor, a very important
but not a decisive one. We have never sinned of historical subjectivism.
We regarded the class struggle -standing on the basis provided by
the productive forces- as the decisive factor, not only at a national
level but also internationally."
Negri and Hardt relapse in such historical subjectivism when they
claim that: "History has a logic only when subjecitivity rules
it, only when (as Nietzsche says) the emergence of subjectivity
reconfigures efficient causes and final causes in the development
of history". Their subjectivism, however, is of a different
type to that mentioned in Trotsky's quote mentioned above. It is
not a subjectivism relying on a revolutionary party. It is neither
a strand of subjectivism stemming from the revolutionary maturity
or learning of the working class, i.e., the process of becoming
a class for itself from a class in itself, the achievement of its
political independence with regards to the bourgeoisie, which only
can be brought about through the experience of the class itself
and its bound with a revolutionary party. This is not the case with
Negri and Hardt,, for whom the becoming of the subject does not
hinge upon these achievements, but rather on ever-present grounds
for liberation.
Building on a logic of an unreal subject ("the multitude")
that bears no correspondence at all with an empirically-set subject,
they proceed to blur the objective positions of the different exploited
classes within the capitalist mode of production, the centrality
of the proletariat in particular as the social subject of the socialist
revolution. Such phantom-like subject built by them, omnipresent
and pure potential, has no need for programmes, strategic and tactics,
let alone a revolutionary party to accomplish its historic mission.
Hence, when the authors of Empire are faced with the setting of
the early 80s and most of the 90s, when neoliberalism gained momentum
and the actual subject is in retreat and atomized, a far cry from
the "constituent flames" of the 70s, their theoretical
framework turns out to be completely unable to deal with reality.
This comes to light when they explain why the U.S. has been able
to hold on to its hegemony throughout the crisis. Thus, they claim
that "The answer lies in large part, perhaps paradoxically,
not in the genius of U.S. politicians or capitalists, but in the
power and creativity of the U.S. proletariat...in terms of the paradigm
of international capitalist command, the U.S. proletariat appears
as the subjective figure that expressed most fully the desires and
needs of international or multinational workers. Against the common
wisdom that the U.S. proletariat is weak because of its low party
and union representation with respect to Europe and elsewhere, perhaps
we should see it as strong for precisely those reasons. Working-class
power resides not in the representative institutions but in the
antagonism and autonomy of the workers themselves...In order to
understand the continuation of U.S. hegemony, then, it is not sufficient
to cite the relations of force that U.S. capitalism wielded over
the capitalists in other countries. U.S. hegemony was actually sustained
by the antagonistic power of the U.S. proletariat" . This is
really surprising. If there is a place where the bourgeoisie in
the last twenty years has been able to overcome the fetters imposed
by labour onto accumulation, that place is the U.S. As the Reagan
onslaught unfolded, and later continued into the 90s, the American
workers endured a massive retreat through a combination of defeats
and the fear of the 1979-82 recession that brought about a hike
of unemployment. It led to a big loss of conquests, a massive wage
loss, the lengthening of the working day, which as a whole allowed
for a significant increase of the rate of exploitation and a recovery
of corporate profits. It is these factors that account for the relative
strength of the U.S. in the face of its competitors and also lay
the basis for its continued hegemony -along with the U.S. privileged
position within the world finance system. Nonetheless, the analysis
proposed by Negri and Hardt writes off this material reality, replacing
it by a subjectivist approach. Thus, the objective balance of forces
between the classes is replaced by the "desires" of the
workers. As to the trade union and political level, it is true that
the union and political representatives of the European workers
is a reformist one or has been bought off by the bourgeoisie. But
celebrating the weakness of the trade union organization and the
lack of any class representation in the American bipartisan system
as proof of strength is nonsensical. The low level of organization
of the American working class is the result of a fierce opposition
of the American bourgeoisie to giving the slightest right of organization
to the workers on one hand, and the political and conservative backwardness
of the working class stemming from the dominant position of the
U.S., on the other. As we see, autonomism and its ultrasubjectivist
approach, whose historical origin goes back to the euphoria of the
struggles in the 60s and the 70s combined with the (justified) repulsion
of many left Marxist intellectuals with Althusser's structuralism
and anti-humanism, is totally unable to understand the present-day
world.
A new "ultra-imperialism"
From such new theoretical framework, it flows that the becoming
of the Empire "as a global order, a new logic and structure
of government, shortly a new form of sovereignty going hand in hand
with the world markets and the world network of production"-
in the words of the authors. When working out their subjectivist
approach to the very end, they dissolve the capitalist competence
and the fight for world supremacy by the rival capitalist states
still at work in the imperialist phase- although disguised in new,
more complex forms- into such "global order".
In the early twentieth century, Kautsky, when analyzing the first
"wave of globalisation", foresaw a progressive withering
away of interimperialist contradictions, a process that should culminate
in "ultraimperialism". In his schema, the international
merger of capital has developed so much so as to make the distinct
economic interests of the different international capital owners
fade away. In his Der Imperialismus, published in Die Neue Zeit
on November 11, 1914, he claimed that: "Thus, from a purely
economic standpoint one cannot rule out that capitalism will outlive
itself to another phase, the cartelisation in foreign policy: a
phase of ultraimperialism, against which we shall, of course, fight
against as resolutely as do against imperialism, but one which poses
dangers of a different kind, not those of an arms race and the threat
to world peace." Lenin did not rule out the possibility that
a bigger concentration and centralization of capital on an international
level may take place. He claimed that the long-term "logic"
tendency led to the establishment of a single world-embracing concern.
But he argued that before such "logical" conclusion should
come about, capitalism would blow itself up as a result of its increased
internal contradictions and the revolutionary struggle of the proletariat
and the oppressed peoples of the world altogether. In his preface
to Bukharin's Imperialism and the World Economy, he wrote: "There
is no question that the development is heading towards a single
world trust that will swallow up al of the enterprises and the states
with no exception. But on the other hand, the development is unfolding
under such circumstances, tempo, contradictions, stand-offs, upheavals
-not only economic ones, but of a political and national kind, etc-
that before we end up with a single world trust, a worldwide 'ultraimperialist'
union of national finance capitals, the break-up of imperialism
shall be inexorably unavoidable and capitalism will be turned into
its contrary."
The key of Lenin's policy lay in the revolutionary perspective,
but one that was not worked out due to sole voluntarism, but one
that flowed from an objective analysis of the contradictions at
work within capitalist development. In this, he differed from Kautsky
and his "profoundly reactionary wish to smooth out the contradictions"
(in Lenin's words), a stand from which his deeply pacifists conclusions
stemmed from.
Negri and Hardt want to emulate Lenin's revolutionary policy and
his struggle for a revolutionary international, in their own words:
"there is an implicit alternative embedded in Lenin's work:
either communist revolution or Empire". But they devoid this
alternative of any objective basis for its realization. If Kautsky,
out of sheer economism, arrives to the theory of "ultraimperialism"
and to deny the existence of contradictions, Negri and Hardt, in
turn, come to the same conclusion through their subject-focused
approach, albeit they do not share the reformist conclusions drawn
by the former. This can be seen in the following argument: "The
analyses of the state and the world market also become possible
in Empire for another reason, becausse at this point in development
class struggle acts without limit on the organization of power.
Having achieved the global level, capitalist development is faced
directly with the multitude, without mediation. Hence the dialectic,
or really the science of the limit and its organization, evaporates.
Class struggle, pushing the nation-state toward its abolition and
thus going beyond the barriers posed by it, proposes the constitution
of Empire as the site of analysis ad conflict. Without the barrier,
then, the situation of struggle is completely open. Capital and
labor are opposed in a directly antagonistic form. This is the fundamental
condition of every political theory of communism."
Such denial of dialectics bears its consequences. Here, there view
of the world reality turns out to be completely abstract. It is
true that the internationalization of the productive forces and
the ensuing internationalization of capital, and the objective basis
for the internationalization of the class struggles with them, have
all increased ten-fold in the last one hundred years, when compared
with the time at which Lenin wrote his notorious pamphlet on imperialism.
Because of this, the need for proletarian internationalism flowing
from such basis has grown stronger than ever. Hence, we share their
criticism of the "thirld world" perspectives, one of the
strongest arguments put forward by them in their new road. But the
authors of Empire wrongly regard the current reality of capitalism
as a tendency, turning the tendency to the internationalization
of capital into a demiurge, which in turn transforms their whole
interpretation of reality into an abstraction that leaves out the
role of mediations. In this way, their methodological approach is
ridden with the same flaws as those Lenin criticized in Kautsky's,
although they regard "ultraimperialism" not as a possibility
(in a "dream" according to the Bolshevik leader) but as
an actual reality. As Lenin said: "In this yearning to turn
away from the reality of imperialism and to take refuge in the pipedream
of the 'ultraimperialism', one we do not know whether or not is
feasible, there is not even the slightest shed of Marxism. Within
such schema Marxism is taken on board for this 'new phase of capitalism'
whose chances of becoming are not even guaranteed by its own creator,
but for the present, already existent, phase, a deeply reactionary
and petty bourgeois yearning to smooth out the contradictions prevails
instead."
Negri's and Hardt's logical operation, paired with their rejection
of dialectics, blurs the actual structure of the world system and
the contradictions flowing from it, i.e., the different hierarchies
of countries within the capitalist world economy both at the centre
and the periphery, the struggle for hegemony between the rival central
powers, the world division between oppressive and oppressed countries
and the concrete intermingling of the working class struggle and
the people's sector in the latter with the masses of imperialist
heartlands, and thus the need to put forward both a revolutionary
tactic and strategy. What comes out of this is an attack against
the Leninist theory of the revolutionary party, since there is no
need to take on the "weakest" link of the imperialist
chain, but rather the "virtual centre" of the Empire can
be conquered from any other point, such as they say in the following
lines. Hence, "From the point of view of the revolutionary
tradition, one might object that the tactical successes of revolutionary
actions in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries were all characterized
precisely by the capacity to blast open the weakest link of the
imperialist chain, that this is the ABC of revolutionary dialectics,
and thus it would seem today that the situation is not very promising.
It is certainly true that the serpentine struggles we are witnessing
today do not provide any clear revolutionary tactics, or maybe they
are completely incomprehensible from the point of view of tactics.
Faced as we are with a series of intensive subversive social movements
that attack the highest levels of imperial organization, however,
it may be no longer usseful to insist on the old distinction between
strategy and tactics. In the constitution of Empire there is no
longer an 'outside' to power and thus no longer weak links-if by
weak link we mean an external point where the articulations of global
power are vulnerable. To achieve significance, every struggle must
attack at the heart of Empire, at its strength. The fact, however,
does not give priority to any geographical regions, as if only social
movements in Washington, Geneva or Tokyo could attack the heart
of Empire. On the contrary, the construction of Empire, and the
globalization of economic and cultural relationships, means that
the virtual center of Empire can be attacked from any point."
It is true that the increased internationalisation of capital has
shortened the distances between the centre and the periphery of
the world, and that the developments in the alter bounce back on
the imperialist heartlands more strongly than in the past. But in
spite of this, the fact remains -even for any sensible observer-
that the U.S. and Indonesia are vulnerable to a very greatly different
degree, to put an extreme case, thus showing the validity of Lenin's
concept of the weakest link as the mainstay of the theory of world
revolution, regarded as a concrete process stemming from the internal
contradictions of world capitalism.
A strange coincidence
We have already said that Negri and Hardt's "theoretical subjectivism"
revolves around an abstract polarization against the views of "theoretical
structuralism" of the world system school and its cyclic patterns
in the historical evolution of capitalism. But quite surprisingly,
and despite this methodological difference, Arrighi in his Long
Twentieth Century arrives at the same conclusion at the onset of
the twenty first century, postulating a structure of the world system
that is quite similar to that of the Empire as a world order of
"globlisation". Thus, he argues that "The modern
interstate system has consequently acquired its present global dimension
through a series of successive hegemonies of an ever-expanding scope
that have consequently reduced the exclusivity of the right of sovereignty
really enjoyed by its member states. If this process were to carry
on, nothing but a true world government such as that contemplated
by Roosevelt would meet the condition that the next world hegemony
should have a territorial and operational scope much extended than
the precedent
Has the western world ruled by the American hegemony
attained such a degree of world power so as to be on the verge of
putting an end to the capitalist history in the way it has been
shaped within the system of expansion of the modern interstate system?
the
obverse of this process of formation of a world government is the
crisis of the territorial states as efficacious instruments of dominion."
Further on, in the conclusion, he postulates, on the basis that
Japan controls world liquidity but remains defenceless on the military
terrain, quite the opposite of the U.S. that still enjoy a de facto
monopolistic control of the use of violence, that: "Such peculiar
configuration of the world power seems to fit perfectly into another
of those 'memorable alliances' between the power of the arms and
the power of money that has pushed forward the capitalist world
economy both in space and time since the late fifteen century. All
those 'memorable alliances', except for the first one, the Iberian-genoese
one, were alliances between entrepreneurial elites and governmental
groups that belonged to the same state: the United Provinces, the
United Kingdom, the United States
"
What is the difference between such views and those holding the
becoming of a "ultraimperialism" such as the ones we have
criticized in Negri? Both views run against Lenin's characterization
of the imperialist phase. It is true that in the early twentieth
century the international concentration of capital "did not
take on the form of an international centralization but rather set
the national imperialist monopolies against each other as antagonists
in the world market of commodities, raw materials and capital."
The formation of monopolies closely linked to their own state that
strived for political and military control of wide geographical
zones laid the basis for a merciless struggle for the scramble of
the world, sometimes through pacific means (tariffs, protectionism,
etc), and when the contradictions burst into the open, it took the
form of an imperialist war.
Ever since then, the international centralization of capital has
grown apace. During the postwar, the expansion of American multinationals
constituted the first great wave. The second wave took place in
the wake of the onset of the crisis of accumulation of capital in
the 70s, one that spread to the American companies and beyond, affecting
the two other poles of the imperialist triad: Japan and Germany.
If the monopolies were a major feature in Lenin's schema, its importance
has increased ten-fold, as shown by the increasing transnationalisation
of the imperialist corporations. The frenzy of mergers and acquisitions,
on a scale encompassing bigger capitals, is aimed at gaining the
share of markets of those concerns or holdings merged.
The growth of these transnational corporations and the sheer size
of their exchanges both between each other and within themselves
have brought about a bigger integration of the world economy. In
other words, such development is the form through which capital
tries to overcome the contradiction between the development of the
productive forces and the limits imposed by the national state.
Nonetheless, as Marx argued with regards to credit, such process
has meant "an abolition of the capitalist mode of production
within the capitalist mode itself", i.e., it has deepened its
contradictions, posing them on a higher level. This has not brought
about a withering away of the state, but a shift of its economic
functions; it is oriented to an ever-increasing scale to guarantee
the reproduction of its own transnational concerns. This is highlighted
by the major role played by the state in the signing of commercial
treaties, in the regulation of competition between rival concerns
in the regions under its control, in implementing measures to boost
a growth in the size of its big concerns, in the negotiations in
the different multilateral agencies such as the WTO, where the different
states strive to protect its groups of interest. All these speak
against analyzing the world economy, if we are to understand it,
without pondering these two aspects of reality, i.e., the level
of the productive forces and the survival of the nation-state as
one of the main contradictions of capitalism nowadays. Likewise,
the introduction of new technology has but deepened this dichotomy.
Thus the chief editor of the Foreign Policy magazine, in an article
titled "New Economy, Old Policy" argues that: "This
reality faces the companies of the new economy with a disquieting
paradox:
the technology companies favour speed, decentralization,
individualism, the disregard for geography, frontiers and sovereignty
altogether. Multilateralism involves a process of slow decision-taking,
obscure aims and a hypersensitivity to any erosion, be it real or
symbolic, of national sovereignty." The view of a "stateless"
corporation bears no resemblance with reality.
The dialectics of the twentieth century
The twentieth century has been, as Eric Hobsbawn puts it, the "age
of extremes". The 1929 crack and the two world wars showed
the convulsive and violent nature of the contradictions embedded
in the development of capitalism. In turn, the revolutionary epoch
ushered in by the Russian Revolution showed the enormous social
might and maturity of the proletariat as a subject of change on
the world arena. Hence the tendency to unilaterally underline any
of these aspects, be it the structural tendencies, be it the tendencies
to the class struggle when pondering the actual dynamics of capitalist
development. Taking just one of these aspects into account, breaking
up the dialectic relationship between them, and endowing it with
an unlimited scope prevents one from reaching a scientific understanding
of reality.
It is here where the materialistic dialectics shows its superiority.
In this sense, Trotsky's concept of "capitalist equilibrium"
enables us to deal with the world system as a whole in a dynamic
fashion. In this respect he pointed out that "capitalist equilibrium
is a complicated phenomenon; the capitalist regime builds up such
equilibrium, then it breaks it up, just to rebuild it and break
it up once again, widening up, in passing, the limits of its dominion.
In the economic sphere, such continuous break-ups and restorations
of equilibrium take on the shape of crisis and booms. In the sphere
of the relationship between the classes, the break up of equilibrium
results in strikes, lock-outs, revolutionary struggle. In the sphere
of the relationships between the states, the break up of equilibrium
brings about war, or else in a veiled way, a war of tariffs, an
economic war or a blockade. Capitalism possesses then a dynamic
equilibrium, which is always undergoing a permanent break up."
Such is the method that enables him to postulate that the break
out of World War I, itself the manifestation of the contradiction
between the development of the productive forces and their constraint
by the capitalist relationships of production and the borders of
the national state, meant a break up of the basis of capitalist
equilibrium and the subsequent opening of a revolutionary epoch.
In that epoch the interaction between the subjective and the objective
elements reaches new heights, being very difficult to distinguish
one another in the works of the economy at times. This is true to
such extent that in the wake of the complete undoing of world commerce
following the 1929 crack and the onset of the decade-long world
economic depression and stagnation, and after the failure of the
revolutions in the 30s due to the betrayals of Stalinism and social
democracy (and their common responsibility for the ascent of nazism),
Trotsky went on to say that "the crisis of mankind is the crisis
of its revolutionary leadership". It was the delay of proletarian
revolution -not as consequence of the lack of heroism or fighting
disposition of the proletariat but as a result of its most subjective
factor: the counterrevolutionary nature of its leadership- what
accounts for the survival of a decomposing capitalism.
In other words, the revolutionary overthrow of capitalism did not
come about because the "opportunist cancer", such as Lenin
defined social democracy, was far stronger. Furthermore, Stalinism
was to reach unheard-of proportions in the wake of World War II,
a time when it became the mainstay of the world status quo, better
known as the "Yalta Order".
Thus, the defeat of fascism at the hands of the Soviet Russia gave
renewed prestige to Stalinism, which used his regained strength
to smash the European revolution and clinch a new deal with the
U.S. to build a new world status quo. Thus, the world witnessed
a contradictory situation in which the might of the Russian degenerate
workers state was used to consolidate the American hegemony, under
which the economic boom set in.
The "partial development" of the productive forces in
the advanced capitalist countries cannot be explained away unless
we take into account the extra economical factors allowing for its
emergence: the derailment of the European revolution at the hands
of Stalinism (which shifted the revolution away towards the colonial
and semicolonial world), the prior destruction of productive forces
provoked by the war, the sheer weakening of the US rival imperialist
states (which enabled the former to rule unchallenged for decades
within the imperialist camp), along with the low wage levels inherited
from fascism. It would also have failed to uphold without the qualitatively
increased economic and political action of the imperialist states
(which introduced all-round social reforms and strengthened the
mechanisms for the cooptation of the union bureaucracies out of
fear of the revolution), the mechanisms of permanent monetary inflation
and the inflation of credit, along with the role played the arms
industry as a "replacement market" in the face of the
overcapitalization of the monopolies. The very "compromise"
of Yalta reflected the contradictory outcome of the war, since it
was in exchange for the concessions given to the mass movement (new
deformed workers' states in the east and social gains the west),
and the cooptation of the union bureaucracy (both of the Stalinist
and Social democratic blend) as guarantors of the world order that
a new order of imperialist rule was set up.
However, the partial development of the productive forces that took
place in the imperialist heartlands during the boom (the growth
of labour productivity was more intense in the 50s and the 60s in
the main imperialist heartlands than in any other previous period)
did not alter the general character of the epoch as one of "crises,
wars and revolutions". Thus, with these peculiarities, the
new "equilibrium" achieved by and large by the agreements
of Yalta and Potsdam did not prevent capitalism from losing a third
of the planet in the years 1948/49, what ultimately expressed at
the same time the fact that the USSR had survived the war and that
capitalism (lacking inner strength) had been forced into a negotiation
with the Stalinist leaders of the Soviet Union. With all these peculiarities
and limits, a new capitalist equilibrium set in and the US economy
finally reach a fresh momentum through the reconstruction of a devastated
Europe - although at a much longer time than Trotsky had predicted.
On the other hand, and in contrast with the capitalist expansion
in the nineteenth century, the proletariat in the second postwar
was already existent in the colonial and semicolonial world, which
witnessed a number of revolutionary (and counterrevolutionary) upheavals
that constantly haunted the relative stability achieved in the imperialist
heartlands. Once again, Stalinism played a crucial role in this
respect, preventing a break-up of the status quo. The postwar boom,
in this context, was far proving capitalism organic strength. It
not only needed of two world wars that wreaked havoc, but also a
pact sealed with Stalinism that was a mainstay of the new equilibrium
achieved.
Capitalism in the last few decades
The backlash of capital in response to the crisis of accumulation
of the 70s, a decade in which the basis of the American hegemony
were massively eroded, was neither due to a cyclic pattern of capitalist
accumulation nor the onset of a fresh phase of capitalist development.
The neoliberal onslaught and the so-called globalisation that went
hand in hand with it was the peculiar form the American backlash
took on. Due to crisis of legitimacy of its world rule fuelled by
the failure in Vietnam, it took advantage of the leverage it exerts
on the international finance system.
The first element, i.e., the weakness of the American might, or
else its lack of legitimacy as the guardian of the world order both
at home and abroad provoked a change in the forms of its interventions,
in order to diminish their impact on its dominion. The "human
rights" policy, the promotion of the NGOs , the substantiation
of the so-called right of intervention in judicial and moral rights,
and the pursuit of "just wars" were the ethos of the US
foreign policy, which from a defensive position in the 70s was turned
into a more offensive policy in subsequent years. It reached its
climax with the so-called triumph of "democracy and the market"
in the wake of the debacle of the so-called socialist countries.
In the 90s, this ideology gained new forces with the intervention
against Iraq, backed by the UN and supported by a wide coalition,
and also in NATO's war in Kosovo, where the imperialist intervention
wrapped itself up in "humanitarian" clothes and the "rescue
of the oppressed masses" . Nonetheless, this "new model
of imperial authority" does not correspond with the new political
order if globalisation, such as Negri and Hardt argue, but to the
constraints imposed on the US might as a result of the yet open
wounds of Vietnam, and the lack of an efficacious legitimating ideology
for its interventionist policy, in the way the threat of Stalinist
gulag had worked before.
The second fundamental factor was - we insist- the privileged position
of the US within the international finance system, one that was
to shape the neoliberal onslaught and globalisation altogether.
In this sense, one cannot but recall a poignant interview conceded
by Trotsky to the New York Times when the depression in the 30s
was raging. When asked: "How do you regard the position of
the US in the present world situation?", Trotsky replied that
he foresaw an ever tightening grip by American capitalism over European
capitalism, and he added that: "However, such inexorable growth
in the US world hegemony will eventually nourish deep contradictions
both in the economy and the politics of the great American republic.
In imposing the dictatorship of the dollar over the world, the American
ruling class will introduce the contradictions of the entire world
in its own dominion" Nowadays, this remark retains a fundamental
methodological value. This is because it has been from the US that
all the attempts at reaching a fresh equilibrium have emanated,
once the basis allowing for the postwar boom came undone. At the
same time, in a complementary and contradictory fashion, the major
factors of instability running through the world economy since the
70s have always revolved around it. This has been the case at the
level of international relationships. The world currency system
codified at Breton Woods was always conditioned and partially implemented,
and although at the onset the US abode by the discipline of tying
the dollar to the gold standard, when such parity was deemed detrimental
for the interests of the US, the Nixon administration just cast
it aside unceremoniously. This meant a way out of the constraints
imposed on the balance of payments, thus giving it an increased
room for manoeuvre in the exchange with other foreign currencies,
but at the cost of increasing the fragility of the international
currency system.
The same can be said with regards to the world finance system and
the American initiative to do away with the state control on capital
flows, a condition also codified in Breton Woods, pushing ahead
with the deregulation and putting international finance flows in
the hands of private financial brokers and the markets, thus turning
New York in the main financial centre in the early 80s.
Another instance of this "dictatorship of the dollar"
over the entire world was the ratification of the Treaty of World
Trade Organisation (WTO) in the past decade, which explicitly states
that the US recognition of its jurisdiction is hinged upon the WTO
being "fair" towards America's interests.
The 90s witnessed a tightening of such positions as a result of
the debacle of the USSR, which left the US with an unchallenged
military supremacy. However, it is its privileged position on a
financial level that has empowered the US to regain its leading
position in the last decade, using it to significantly limit the
ability of rival imperialist centres to deal with their internal
affairs in an autonomous fashion.
It is here that we are to find the capital difference between the
basis of the British hegemony in the nineteenth century and those
of the American rule in the twentieth century. Albeit Arrighi in
his books paves the way for researching into the new modalities
acquired by the development of the American hegemony and its decline
compared with its predecessors , the school of the world system
and its cyclic pattern is inadequate to grasp this qualitative difference
stemming from the imperialist nature of the epoch we live in. While
the British hegemony rested upon an extension of its frontiers in
the direction of its new territories, its unfolding did not block
the emergence of other powers such as the US and Germany directly.
The "equilibrium of power", the ethos of British diplomacy
vis-à-vis the different European powers, had a rather negative
character: it meant reassuring that no other power should dominate
the continent. Britain itself did not have the ability, nor the
willingness, to rule over Europe on its own. Quite otherwise, the
American hegemony rests upon the need of the capitalist states of
dominating the economy of all the continents, capital investments,
preferential commercial agreements, currency regulations and political
control altogether. It is a matter of subordinating not only the
less developed world but other industrialized states as well, be
them enemies or allies, to the priorities of the accumulation of
capital of the hegemonic power. This weighs upon the conditions
for the emergence of powers questioning the rule of the old hegemón:
not only due to the fact that the scramble of the world has been
done already (although the disintegration of the postcapitalist
economies has created a new geographical area of dominion and dispute
for capital), but, more important still, due to the increased subordination
of those centres to the dictates of the accumulation of the ruling
nation of the ancient order that holds back and delays the search
for more autonomy.
However, the fact that we point to this development does not mean
that we foresee the emergence of a "superimperialism"
as the most likely event, such as the proponents of the twenty first
as another "American century" claim once and again. A
man coming from the inner circle of the American establishment,
the conservative Henry Kissinger, has provided the most accurate
prognosis as to its actual strength: "What is really new in
the nascent world order is that, for the first time, the US cannot
retreat from the world nor dominate it
When the US entered
the world arena they were young and robust, and the necessary might
to make the world adopt its view of the international relationships.
At the end of Second World War, in 1945, the US were so powerful
(at some time, 35% of the world economic output was American), that
it seemed that they were poised to shape the world according to
their preferences
Three decades later, the US are not in the
same position to push ahead with the immediate satisfaction of its
desires. Other countries have reached out to the status of big powers."
In turn, it is the very existence of such other big powers that
makes of the tendency to "ultraimperialism" an untenable
view. Its advocates rely on the bigger integration of the world
economy as a result of the accelerated centralization of capital
worldwide, a process that has been unfolding ever since the crisis
of accumulation of the 70s broke out, one that has been mainly fuelled
by American capital. The tendency to an increased interimperialist
competition, no matter it takes veiled forms, is today more noticeable
than ever before. The increasing merger of capitals on a continental
level has fuelled a renewed competition between blocs of power of
continental scope, like the imperialist triad (the US and the NAFTA
and his attempt to extend it to the FTAA, the EU and his expansion
towards Eastern Europe, and to a lesser extent, Japan and the Pacific
rim). So far, this interimperialist competition has taken a "benign"
form, expressing itself has a heightened commercial competence,
more mergers and acquisitions seeking to limit concurrence, the
increase in direct investment in the imperialist countries themselves,
etc. The likelihood that the American economy, which was the most
stabilizing and dynamic factor of the world economy in the last
decade, might go through a deep downturn, combining with the depression
of the Japanese economy, thus ushering in the perspective of a world
recession, might all herald a more vitriolic interimperialist competition
that should lead to an all-round hike in tariffs which in turn might
entangle the networks of world commerce. Both the American think-tank
Stratfor and the British magazine The Economist hold that this perspective
is likely to materialize. The former claims that: "In the past
decade, there was a general consensus in favour of free trade, casting
aside the protectionist forces. The reason was less ideological
than empirical, the policy of free trade went along with the prosperity
In
bad times, however, the relationship between free trade, protectionism
and the economic performance becomes more problematic. As long as
unemployment grows, the bankruptcies go up and life becomes more
difficult, the foreign imports to the American market and the difficulty
of exporting to foreign markets fuel by far more resistance. Much
more than fuelling intolerance towards interventions abroad, the
recessions make the Americans think that other countries are direct
threats to the prosperity, and even agents of the economic failure.
Things can get sour very rapidly. The powerhouse of international
relationships can get dramatically altered when its centre of gravity
becomes suspicious and hostile." The Economist claims that:
"The GDP of the world has not fallen at any year since 1930.
Even during the oil crisis of the 70s, the world GDP grew. A truly
global recession would not only be painful, but would bring about
immense dangers, encouraging the countries to retreat once again
behind protectionist barriers. With luck and some skill, a global
slump might be avoided. The policy makers should be ready to stand
by the economies, if need be, by lowering interest rates and taxes
altogether. They should also make sure that the first recession
of the new world economy does not bring about a reversal of globalisation
itself."
In this framework, with the phantom of the "old" protectionism
haunting the world economy, the postmodernist novelty of an "Empire"
that "does not establish any centre of territorial power and
does not rely on fixed borders or barriers" sounds at best
like a mere exaggeration of some conjuncture tendencies of the world
economy, or else worse, a mere phantasmogorical ruse that is unable
to predict the dynamic of the system, let alone to provide a scientific
basis to fight against it.
Where is the world system going at the onset
of the twenty first century?
We are not heading towards the Empire nor to the emergence of a
"superimperialism", but to an epoch of heightened crises,
wars and revolutions, which under new guises and changing balances
of forces cut across the reality of contemporary capitalism.
The last period of the twentieth century, particularly the last
decade, witnessed a strengthening of the American supremacy, as
opposed to the 70s, a time when its historical decline began. The
collapse of Stalinism, along with the victory of the imperialist
coalition in the Gulf War boosted the neoliberal onslaught worldwide.
The withering away of what Arrighi and Hardt call the "second
periphery", along with the imperialist backlash against the
semicolonial countries, which integrated these more openly into
the world economy (the so-called "emerging markets"),
meant a widening of the geographical scope of capital. In turn,
the weakening of the rival imperialist nations and of the so-called
"Rhineland" and "Nippon" models, and their submission
to the US' dynamics of accumulation (financing the American commercial
deficit, as shareholders and direct investors, through the process
of mergers and acquisitions, etc) is what explains that the reinforcement
of the American rule took on the form of a break-through of "globalised"
capitalism- hand in hand with the extension to new geographical
frontiers.
Those who speak of Empire are just adapting their view to this appearance,
working out from such peculiarities and the conjuncture tendencies
of imperialist politics in the last period -the last decade in particular-
the characteristics of a supposedly new phase of capitalism. They
commit the same methodological mistake as the high priest of Marxist
revisionism, Eduard Bernstein, although without drawing openly reformist
conclusions. The former, when writing at the end of the great 1873-96
depression and the onset of the belle époque of European
capitalism, when it went through one of its biggest booms worldwide
that brought about improved living and work conditions for some
layers of the industrial proletariat (what Lenin's Marxism branded
the "labour aristocracy"), saw no reasons why those tendencies
might be reversed in a foreseeable future. The 1914 war and the
crisis of bourgeois society that broke out at the time settled that
debate and were a cruel reminder of how dangerous is to forget the
dialectics (i.e., the laws that lay bare motion) when analyzing
reality.
Against this methodological mistake and the conclusions that flow
from it that many thinkers of contemporary capitalism relapse into
nowadays, the 90s did not hallmark the emergence of a global empire
nor a "superimperialism", but rather ushered in an interregnum
of "unstable US rule" opposed to the period of absolute
hegemony that followed the Second World War.
The illusions of the early 90s as to the emergency of a "new
world order" that went hand in hand with "globalisation"
are coming up against the stumbling block of reality at the end
of the same decade. The downfall of the USSR, albeit it has brought
about a geographical extension for the rule of capital, has not
yet provided a "historical" new lease of life (a new boom)
for it, which would mean its complete transformation in semicolonies.
Quite otherwise, the smashing up of the old order of rule, which
had in the Stalinist bureaucracy one of its mainstays, has not yet
been replaced by a reactionary new world order. Moreover, it has
ushered in a period of clashes between the classes, the relationships
between the states and the economy worldwide, where the contradictions
in the formerly called socialist countries are one of the main sources
of destabilization.
In the current period, the loss of its Stalinist ally leaves the
US more lonely and exposed to deal with the contradictions running
deep in the world arena, within a world system split into a imperialist
triad (the US, Germany and Japan) of competing powers rivaling the
American hegemony, especially in the sphere of the economy, increasingly
in the level of politics, and still lagging behind in the military
level, where the US remains unchallenged.
If the in the past decade these realities were "hidden",
the end of the cycle of American economic growth and its destabilizing
consequences for the rest of the economies worldwide, along with
the strong tensions running through the system of interstate relationships
are making them come to the surface. This is noticeable in the shift
under way in the foreign policy of the recently sworn-in Bush administration
that is leaving behind any pretence of "universalism"
typical of the Clinton administration, and is going for a increasingly
"unilateral" policy prioritizing the "defence of
national interest", even at the risk of jeopardizing the relationships
with the other big powers. Stratfor has taken notice of these shifts,
claiming in its latest reports that: "The last few weeks have
witnessed the tensions between the US and both Russia and China.
This period will be remembered as the end of the post cold war period,
and the onset of a new period of the international relationships
The
structure of the world system is at stake here. Two big powers want
to see a more multipolar world. The only superpower wants, understandably,
to uphold the status quo, a unipolar system." The "calm"
period of the 90s and the bourgeois optimism that the world, after
the "defeat of communism" was heading to and unlimited
period of prosperity and less cashes is now behind us. As Stratfor
claims: "Washington took this state of affairs as guaranteed,
a hallmark of the post cold war period. The economic prosperity
of the 90s allowed for this diplomatic carelessness. Russia's and
China's natural inclination to resist the US military and political
power was countered by theirs interest in maintaining friendly economic
relationships". For Stratfor the forthcoming scenario is not
simply a "reversal" to the cold war period, as the rhetoric
of the new Bush administration might seem to indicate, but to a
more intricate scenario of international relationships, and this
for two reasons: "First, neither Russia nor China might have
domestic political stability so as to pursue their policies in the
long term. Secondly, it is not yet clear if other countries will
rally to resist the US. Japan will go soon through some dramatic
changes, due to its untenable economic situation, while the political
evolution of Europe with regards to the US is grimmer every time.
In any of these cases, we are not facing a new cold war. This a
world that has few precedents, one in which a superpower confronts
several big powers trying to control it. The postwar period has
passed away and cannot be resuscitated. All that is missing in this
new period is a good name."
Although this overview of emerging world situation is heavily biased
towards the interstate relationships, as every bourgeois geopolitical
analysis, it is useful to get a less "romantic" and "naïve"
picture of the world system and the class struggle than that depicted
by the authors of Empire, one devoid of contradictions and mediations.
In the face of a world heading to increasingly deeper disputes and
tensions between the main imperialist powers, between these and
the former "communist" countries, between the centre and
the semicolonies, with economic crises, saber-rattling and wider
gaps between "those at the top" and a potentially heightened
class struggle, the logic of the imperialist epoch as one of "crises,
wars and revolutions" retains its full validity. This does
not mean scholastically ruminating the old categories, but updating
them incorporating the following elements that we have explicated
in this article, which we now detail in summary. They are: a) the
increased integration of the world economy and thus of the class
struggle with a more decisive weight of the working class in most
of the countries of the world (as shown by the growth of wage-earners
in major regions of the periphery, and also the fact that most of
the world population lives in the cities) than at the onset of the
twentieth century; b) the weakness of the counterrevolutionary misleaderships
that, first with the Social democracy and Stalinism then, were a
major bulwark to contain the upsurge of the mass movement in the
last century; c) the exacerbation of the interimperialist competence,
one that starts from a massive unevenness between the old hegemonic
power -whose rule relies upon the unprecedented control of the fundamental
economic and military levers of worldwide accumulation- and the
emerging powers, a factor holding back and delaying the alteration
of the status quo of the world; d) the tendency to the formation
of a "pool" of imperialist powers, no matter how unstable
and utopian such endeavour might be, that in spite of their counter
posed national interests have taken decisive steps towards supranational
unification (European Union) as way of counteracting the unevenness
of the components of interstate system mentioned in the last item;
e) the yet indefinite social nature of the process of restoration-semicolonisation
of the former degenerate and deformed big workers states, Russia
and its sphere of influence and China.
Taking up the classical theory of imperialism in a creative fashion
is a key task to appraise the complex and intricate reality of the
world today.
NOTAS
1 Arrighi G. "El largo siglo XX." Editorial Akal -1999.
2 "... la expansión material del primer ciclo sistémico
de acumulación (genovés) fue promovida y organizada
por una agencia dicotómica formada por un elemento aristocrático
-territorialista (ibérico), que se especializó en
el suministro de protección y en la obtención de poder,
y por un elemento capitalista burgués, que se especializó
en la compraventa de mercancías y en la búsqueda de
beneficios." Idem 1 pág. 148.
3 "El mayor poder del estado holandés frente al genovés
permitió a la clase capitalista holandesa hacer lo que los
genoveses ya habían estado haciendo: convertir la competencia
interestatal en búsqueda de inversión en un mecanismo
para la autoexpansión de su propio capital, pero sin tener
que 'comprar' protección desde estados territorialistas como
había tenido que hacer Génova" Idem 1 pág.
261.
4 Idem 1 pág. 261
5 Idem 1 pág. 261
6 Algunos autores como André Günder Frank van incluso
más atrás y rastrean este origen hace 5000 años.
7 Mandel E. "El capitalismo tardío"
8 Marx K. "El Capital" Tomo III.
9 Idem 7. El mismo autor señala que había dos grandes
obstáculos para el dominio del capital extranjero sobre las
economías capitalistas nacientes: 1- La magnitud de la acumulación
capitalista en los países centrales no era suficiente para
que este capital fuera a comprometerse en el establecimiento de
fábricas en otras regiones del mundo. 2- Lo inadecuado de
los medios de comunicación: el desarrollo desigual de la
Revolución Industrial en la manufactura y en la industria
del transporte.
10 Idem 7.
11 Idem 1 pág. 195/ 196.
12 Entre 1876 y 1914 las potencias europeas se anexaron unos once
millones de millas cuadradas de territorio, principalmente en Asia
y Africa.
13 Marx K. El Capital.
14 OP.citada.
15 Negri A. - Hardt M. "Empire" editorial Harvard University
Press - 2000. Preface xii
16 Idem 15.
17 Idem 15 Preface xiii y xiv
18 Idem 15 Capitulo 3.1 "The limits of imperialism". Pág.
239. Las negritas son nuestras.
19 Anderson P. "Teoría, política e historia".
Debate con E.P. Thompson.
20 Idem 15 Capitulo 1.3 "Alternatives Within Empire" pág.
43.
21 Idem 15 Capitulo 3.1 "The limits of Imperialism" pág.
234-235
22 Trotsky L. "Bolchevismo y stalinismo". Editorial El
yunque. En esta cita Trotsky está discutiendo contra un "subjetivismo
histórico" que acusaba al Partido Bolchevique de ser
responsable del stalinismo.
Sin embargo, esta cita, sirve metodológicamente para ver
la concepción que tenía Trotsky de la agencia humana
(en su máxima expresión: la unidad entre partido y
masas autodeterminadas) y la relación de esta con los elementos
objetivos.
23 Idem 15 Cap. 3.3 "Resistance, Crisis, Transformation."
Pág. 268-269.
24 Citado en "El capitalismo tardío" de Mandel
E., Ed. Era
25 Bujarin N. "La economía mundial y el imperialismo"
Cuadernos de Pasado y Presente- 1984.
26 Idem 15 Cap. 3.1 "The Limits of Imperialism" pág.
237
27 "Las perspectivas Tercermundistas, que antes pudieron ser
de alguna utilidad, eran ahora totalmente inútiles. Entendemos
que el Tercermundismo se define por la noción que la contradicción
primaria y el antagonismo en el sistema capitalista internacional
está entre el capital del Primer Mundo y el trabajo del Tercer
Mundo. Entonces, el potencial revolucionario reside exclusivamente
en el Tercer Mundo. Esta visión ha sido evocada implícita
o explícitamente en numerosas teorías de la dependencia,
del subdesarrollo y perspectivas del sistema mundo. El limitado
mérito de la perspectiva Tercermundista reside en que se
opone directamente al "Primermundismo", o la visión
eurocéntrica que considera que la innovación y los
cambios se originan, y sólo pueden originarse, en Euro-América.
Sin embargo, su oposición especular a esta falsa visión
conduce a una postura igualmente falsa. Hallamos inadecuada a esta
perspectiva Tercermundista porque ignora las innovaciones y antagonismos
del trabajo en el Primer y Segundo Mundo. Más aún,
y más importante para nuestra argumentación, la perspectiva
Tercermundista es ciega a la convergencia efectiva de luchas en
todo el mundo, tanto en los países dominantes como en los
subordinados" "Empire" Cap. 3.3 "Resistance,
Crisis, Transformation" pág. 264.
28 Idem 25.
29 Idem 15 Cap. 1.3 "Alternatives Within Empire" Pág.
58-59
30 Idem 1 pág. 96-97.
31 Idem 1 pág. 426.
32 Idem 7
33 "New Economy, Old Politics", Financial Times 22-12-00
34 Trotsky L. "Informe al Tercer Congreso de la Internacional
Comunista." en " Naturaleza y dinámica del capitalismo
y la economía de transición" CEIP - León
Trotsky. - 2000.
35 Como dice Trotsky: "La última guerra imperialista
constituyó el acontecimiento que, acertadamente, consideramos
como un golpe terrible, sin precedente histórico, asestado
al equilibrio del mundo capitalista. Es así que, después
de la guerra, comienza la época de los grandes movimientos
de masas y de las luchas revolucionarias. Rusia, el más débil
de los eslabones que formaban la cadena capitalista, fue quien primero
perdió su equilibrio, y también quien antes ingresó
en la vía revolucionaria". " La situación
mundial, junio de 1921". Naturaleza y dinámica del capitalismo...
CEIP L. Trotsky -2000
36 Más allá de que no concordemos con su definición
de "Imperio", la descripción de los autores sobre
las ONGs es realmente apropiada. En su libro dicen: " Estas
ONG humanitarias son, en efecto, (aún cuando esto vaya contra
las intenciones de sus integrantes) algunas de las armas pacíficas
más poderosas del nuevo orden mundial - las campañas
caritativas y las órdenes mendicantes del Imperio. Estas
ONG conducen "guerras justas" sin armas, sin violencia,
sin fronteras. Como los Dominicos en el período medieval
tardío y los Jesuitas en el alba de la modernidad, estos
grupos se esfuerzan por identificar las necesidades universales
y defender los derechos humanos. Por medio de su lenguaje y su acción,
definen primero al enemigo como privación (en la esperanza
de prevenir daños serios) y luego reconocen al enemigo como
pecado". Idem 15 cap. 1.2 "Biopolitical Production"
pág. 36.
37 Esto lo que le da pie para decir a Negri y Hardt que: "Todas
las intervenciones de los ejércitos imperiales son solicitadas
por una o más de las partes involucradas en un conflicto
ya existente. El Imperio no nace por su propia voluntad, sino que
es llamado a ser y constituirse sobre la base de su capacidad para
resolver conflictos. El Imperio se conforma y sus intervenciones
se vuelven jurídicamente legitimadas sólo cuando se
ha insertado en la cadena de consenso internacional orientada a
resolver conflictos existentes". Idem 15 cap. 1.1 "World
Order" pág.15
38 Trotsky L. "Entrevista al New York Times" 5 de marzo
de 1932. Escritos.
39 Como ilustran la presión monetaria ejercida contra la
estrategia keynesiana de crecimiento bajo el primer gobierno de
Miterrand en los años '80, o las constantes presiones de
apertura de las finanzas japonesas a los operadores norteamericanos,
o los acuerdos de restricción del comercio del primero sobre
el segundo.
40 Arrighi en su libro plantea que: "En la actualidad, sin
embargo, es el régimen estadounidense el que está
siendo sustituido, siendo la nación rica en activos (Japón)
y la nación dominante del viejo orden (EE.UU) radicalmente
diferente de la relación existente entre los EE.UU y el Reino
Unido durante la primera mitad del siglo XX". Idem 1 pág.
425.
41 En este caso una sola superpotencia imperialista posee tal hegemonía
que las otras potencias imperialistas pierden toda independencia
real frente a ella y quedan reducidas a la condición de pequeñas
potencias semicoloniales.
42 Kissinger H. "La diplomacia." Ed. Fondo de Cultura
Económica - 1995.
43 Stratfor, 22/3/01.
44 The Economist, 22/3/01
45 Agencia Stratfor, "The end of the post-cold war era",
9/4/2001
|